jupytext | kernelspec | ||||||||||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
|
|
This lecture is a sequel or prequel to {doc}cagan_ree
.
We'll use linear algebra to do some experiments with an alternative "monetarist" or "fiscal" theory of price levels.
Like the model in {doc}cagan_ree
, the model asserts that when a government persistently spends more than it collects in taxes and prints money to finance the shortfall, it puts upward pressure on the price level and generates persistent inflation.
Instead of the "perfect foresight" or "rational expectations" version of the model in {doc}cagan_ree
, our model in the present lecture is an "adaptive expectations" version of a model that {cite}Cagan
used to study the monetary dynamics of hyperinflations.
It combines these components:
-
a demand function for real money balances that asserts that the logarithm of the quantity of real balances demanded depends inversely on the public's expected rate of inflation
-
an adaptive expectations model that describes how the public's anticipated rate of inflation responds to past values of actual inflation
-
an equilibrium condition that equates the demand for money to the supply
-
an exogenous sequence of rates of growth of the money supply
Our model stays quite close to Cagan's original specification.
As in {doc}pv
and {doc}cons_smooth
, the only linear algebra operations that we'll be using are matrix multiplication and matrix inversion.
To facilitate using linear matrix algebra as our principal mathematical tool, we'll use a finite horizon version of the model.
Let
- $ m_t $ be the log of the supply of nominal money balances;
- $\mu_t = m_{t+1} - m_t $ be the net rate of growth of nominal balances;
- $p_t $ be the log of the price level;
- $\pi_t = p_{t+1} - p_t $ be the net rate of inflation between
$t$ and $ t+1$; -
$\pi_t^*$ be the public's expected rate of inflation between$t$ and$t+1$ ; -
$T$ the horizon -- i.e., the last period for which the model will determine$p_t$ -
$\pi_0^*$ public's initial expected rate of inflation between time$0$ and time$1$ .
The demand for real balances
$$
m_t^d - p_t = -\alpha \pi_t^* : , : \alpha > 0 ; \quad t = 0, 1, \ldots, T .
$$ (eq:caganmd_ad)
This equation asserts that the demand for real balances
is inversely related to the public's expected rate of inflation with sensitivity
Equating the logarithm eq:caganmd_ad
and solving for the logarithm
$$ p_t = m_t + \alpha \pi_t^* $$ (eq:eqfiscth1)
Taking the difference between equation {eq}eq:eqfiscth1
at time
$$ \pi_t = \mu_t + \alpha \pi_{t+1}^* - \alpha \pi_t^* $$ (eq:eqpipi)
We assume that the expected rate of inflation Friedman1956
and {cite}Cagan
, where
$$ \pi_{t+1}^* = \lambda \pi_t^* + (1 -\lambda) \pi_t $$ (eq:adaptexpn)
As exogenous inputs into the model, we take initial conditions
As endogenous outputs of our model we want to find sequences $\pi = {\pi_t}{t=0}^T, p = {p_t}{t=0}^T$ as functions of the exogenous inputs.
We'll do some mental experiments by studying how the model outputs vary as we vary the model inputs.
We begin by writing the equation {eq}eq:adaptexpn
adaptive expectations model for
Write this equation as
$$ A \pi^* = (1-\lambda) B \pi + \pi_0^* $$ (eq:eq1)
where the $(T+2) \times (T+2) $matrix
Next we write the key equation {eq}eq:eqpipi
in matrix notation as
$$ \begin{bmatrix} \pi_0 \cr \pi_1 \cr \pi_1 \cr \vdots \cr \pi_T \end{bmatrix} = \begin{bmatrix} \mu_0 \cr \mu_1 \cr \mu_2 \cr \vdots \cr \mu_T \end{bmatrix}
- \begin{bmatrix} - \alpha & \alpha & 0 & \cdots & 0 & 0 \cr 0 & -\alpha & \alpha & \cdots & 0 & 0 \cr 0 & 0 & -\alpha & \cdots & 0 & 0 \cr \vdots & \vdots & \vdots & \cdots & \alpha & 0 \cr 0 & 0 & 0 & \cdots & -\alpha & \alpha \end{bmatrix} \begin{bmatrix} \pi_0^* \cr \pi_1^* \cr \pi_2^* \cr \vdots \cr \pi_{T+1}^* \end{bmatrix} $$
Represent the previous equation system in terms of vectors and matrices as
$$ \pi = \mu + C \pi^* $$ (eq:eq2)
where the
We now have all of the ingredients we need to solve for
Combine equations {eq}eq:eq1
and {eq}eq:eq2
to get
which implies that
Multiplying both sides of the above equation by the inverse of the matrix on the left side gives
$$ \pi^* = \left[ A - (1-\lambda) B C \right]^{-1} \left[ (1-\lambda) B \mu+ \pi_0^* \right] $$ (eq:eq4)
Having solved equation {eq}eq:eq4
for eq:eq2
to solve for
We have thus solved for two of the key endogenous time series determined by our model, namely, the sequence
Knowing these, we can then quickly calculate the associated sequence eq:eqfiscth1
.
Let's fill in the details for this step.
Since we now know
Thus, notice that we can represent the equations
as the matrix equation
$$
\begin{bmatrix}
1 & 0 & 0 & \cdots & 0 & 0 \cr
-1 & 1 & 0 & \cdots & 0 & 0 \cr
0 & -1 & 1 & \cdots & 0 & 0 \cr
\vdots & \vdots & \vdots & \vdots & 0 & 0 \cr
0 & 0 & 0 & \cdots & 1 & 0 \cr
0 & 0 & 0 & \cdots & -1 & 1
\end{bmatrix}
\begin{bmatrix}
m_1 \cr m_2 \cr m_3 \cr \vdots \cr m_T \cr m_{T+1}
\end{bmatrix}
= \begin{bmatrix}
\mu_0 \cr \mu_1 \cr \mu_2 \cr \vdots \cr \mu_{T-1} \cr \mu_T
\end{bmatrix}
- \begin{bmatrix}
m_0 \cr 0 \cr 0 \cr \vdots \cr 0 \cr 0 \end{bmatrix} $$ (eq:eq101_ad)
Multiplying both sides of equation {eq}eq:eq101_ad
with the inverse of the matrix on the left will give
$$ m_t = m_0 + \sum_{s=0}^{t-1} \mu_s, \quad t =1, \ldots, T+1 $$ (eq:mcum_ad)
Equation {eq}eq:mcum_ad
shows that the log of the money supply at
We can then compute eq:eqfiscth1
.
We can write a compact formula for $p $ as
where
which is just
Our computations will verify that
so that in general
$$ \pi_t^* \neq \pi_t, \quad t = 0, 1, \ldots , T $$ (eq:notre)
This outcome is typical in models in which adaptive expectations hypothesis like equation {eq}eq:adaptexpn
appear as a
component.
In {doc}cagan_ree
, we studied a version of the model that replaces hypothesis {eq}eq:adaptexpn
with
a "perfect foresight" or "rational expectations" hypothesis.
But now, let's dive in and do some computations with the adaptive expectations version of the model.
As usual, we'll start by importing some Python modules.
import numpy as np
from collections import namedtuple
import matplotlib.pyplot as plt
Cagan_Adaptive = namedtuple("Cagan_Adaptive",
["α", "m0", "Eπ0", "T", "λ"])
def create_cagan_adaptive_model(α = 5, m0 = 1, Eπ0 = 0.5, T=80, λ = 0.9):
return Cagan_Adaptive(α, m0, Eπ0, T, λ)
md = create_cagan_adaptive_model()
+++ {"user_expressions": []}
We solve the model and plot variables of interests using the following functions.
def solve_cagan_adaptive(model, μ_seq):
" Solve the Cagan model in finite time. "
α, m0, Eπ0, T, λ = model
A = np.eye(T+2, T+2) - λ*np.eye(T+2, T+2, k=-1)
B = np.eye(T+2, T+1, k=-1)
C = -α*np.eye(T+1, T+2) + α*np.eye(T+1, T+2, k=1)
Eπ0_seq = np.append(Eπ0, np.zeros(T+1))
# Eπ_seq is of length T+2
Eπ_seq = np.linalg.solve(A - (1-λ)*B @ C, (1-λ) * B @ μ_seq + Eπ0_seq)
# π_seq is of length T+1
π_seq = μ_seq + C @ Eπ_seq
D = np.eye(T+1, T+1) - np.eye(T+1, T+1, k=-1) # D is the coefficient matrix in Equation (14.8)
m0_seq = np.append(m0, np.zeros(T))
# m_seq is of length T+2
m_seq = np.linalg.solve(D, μ_seq + m0_seq)
m_seq = np.append(m0, m_seq)
# p_seq is of length T+2
p_seq = m_seq + α * Eπ_seq
return π_seq, Eπ_seq, m_seq, p_seq
+++ {"user_expressions": []}
def solve_and_plot(model, μ_seq):
π_seq, Eπ_seq, m_seq, p_seq = solve_cagan_adaptive(model, μ_seq)
T_seq = range(model.T+2)
fig, ax = plt.subplots(5, 1, figsize=[5, 12], dpi=200)
ax[0].plot(T_seq[:-1], μ_seq)
ax[1].plot(T_seq[:-1], π_seq, label=r'$\pi_t$')
ax[1].plot(T_seq, Eπ_seq, label=r'$\pi^{*}_{t}$')
ax[2].plot(T_seq, m_seq - p_seq)
ax[3].plot(T_seq, m_seq)
ax[4].plot(T_seq, p_seq)
y_labs = [r'$\mu$', r'$\pi$', r'$m - p$', r'$m$', r'$p$']
subplot_title = [r'Money supply growth', r'Inflation', r'Real balances', r'Money supply', r'Price level']
for i in range(5):
ax[i].set_xlabel(r'$t$')
ax[i].set_ylabel(y_labs[i])
ax[i].set_title(subplot_title[i])
ax[1].legend()
plt.tight_layout()
plt.show()
return π_seq, Eπ_seq, m_seq, p_seq
+++ {"user_expressions": []}
In constructing our examples, we shall assume that
$$ \Bigl| \frac{\lambda-\alpha(1-\lambda)}{1-\alpha(1-\lambda)} \Bigr| < 1 $$ (eq:suffcond)
The source of this condition is the following string of deductions:
$$ \begin{aligned} \pi_{t}&=\mu_{t}+\alpha\pi_{t+1}^{}-\alpha\pi_{t}^{}\\pi_{t+1}^{}&=\lambda\pi_{t}^{}+(1-\lambda)\pi_{t}\\pi_{t}&=\frac{\mu_{t}}{1-\alpha(1-\lambda)}-\frac{\alpha(1-\lambda)}{1-\alpha(1-\lambda)}\pi_{t}^{}\\implies\pi_{t}^{}&=\frac{1}{\alpha(1-\lambda)}\mu_{t}-\frac{1-\alpha(1-\lambda)}{\alpha(1-\lambda)}\pi_{t}\\pi_{t+1}&=\frac{\mu_{t+1}}{1-\alpha(1-\lambda)}-\frac{\alpha(1-\lambda)}{1-\alpha(1-\lambda)}\left(\lambda\pi_{t}^{*}+(1-\lambda)\pi_{t}\right)\&=\frac{\mu_{t+1}}{1-\alpha(1-\lambda)}-\frac{\lambda}{1-\alpha(1-\lambda)}\mu_{t}+\frac{\lambda-\alpha(1-\lambda)}{1-\alpha(1-\lambda)}\pi_{t} \end{aligned} $$
By assuring that the coefficient on eq:suffcond
assures stability of the dynamics of
The reader is free to study outcomes in examples that violate condition {eq}eq:suffcond
.
print(np.abs((md.λ - md.α*(1-md.λ))/(1 - md.α*(1-md.λ))))
Now we'll turn to some experiments.
We'll study a situation in which the rate of growth of the money supply is
Thus, let
So where
Notice that we studied exactly this experiment in a rational expectations version of the model in {doc}cagan_ree
.
So by comparing outcomes across the two lectures, we can learn about consequences of assuming adaptive expectations, as we do here, instead of rational expectations as we assumed in that other lecture.
# Parameters for the experiment 1
T1 = 60
μ0 = 0.5
μ_star = 0
μ_seq_1 = np.append(μ0*np.ones(T1), μ_star*np.ones(md.T+1-T1))
# solve and plot
π_seq_1, Eπ_seq_1, m_seq_1, p_seq_1 = solve_and_plot(md, μ_seq_1)
We invite the reader to compare outcomes with those under rational expectations studied in {doc}cagan_ree
.
Please note how the actual inflation rate
We invite you to explain to yourself the source of this overshooting and why it does not occur in the rational expectations version of the model.
Now we'll do a different experiment, namely, a gradual stabilization in which the rate of growth of the money supply smoothly decline from a high value to a persistently low value.
While price level inflation eventually falls, it falls more slowly than the driving force that ultimately causes it to fall, namely, the falling rate of growth of the money supply.
The sluggish fall in inflation is explained by how anticipated inflation
# parameters
ϕ = 0.9
μ_seq_2 = np.array([ϕ**t * μ0 + (1-ϕ**t)*μ_star for t in range(md.T)])
μ_seq_2 = np.append(μ_seq_2, μ_star)
# solve and plot
π_seq_2, Eπ_seq_2, m_seq_2, p_seq_2 = solve_and_plot(md, μ_seq_2)