jupytext | kernelspec | ||||||||||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
|
|
This lecture requires the following imports and installs before we proceed.
:tags: [hide-output]
!pip install quantecon_book_networks
!pip install quantecon
!pip install pandas-datareader
import numpy as np
import networkx as nx
import matplotlib.pyplot as plt
import quantecon_book_networks
import quantecon_book_networks.input_output as qbn_io
import quantecon_book_networks.plotting as qbn_plt
import quantecon_book_networks.data as qbn_data
import matplotlib as mpl
from matplotlib.patches import Polygon
quantecon_book_networks.config("matplotlib")
mpl.rcParams.update(mpl.rcParamsDefault)
The following figure illustrates a network of linkages among 15 sectors obtained from the US Bureau of Economic Analysis’s 2021 Input-Output Accounts Data.
:tags: [hide-cell]
def build_coefficient_matrices(Z, X):
"""
Build coefficient matrices A and F from Z and X via
A[i, j] = Z[i, j] / X[j]
F[i, j] = Z[i, j] / X[i]
"""
A, F = np.empty_like(Z), np.empty_like(Z)
n = A.shape[0]
for i in range(n):
for j in range(n):
A[i, j] = Z[i, j] / X[j]
F[i, j] = Z[i, j] / X[i]
return A, F
ch2_data = qbn_data.production()
codes = ch2_data["us_sectors_15"]["codes"]
Z = ch2_data["us_sectors_15"]["adjacency_matrix"]
X = ch2_data["us_sectors_15"]["total_industry_sales"]
A, F = build_coefficient_matrices(Z, X)
---
mystnb:
figure:
caption: US 15 sector production network
name: us_15sectors
tags: [hide-input]
---
centrality = qbn_io.eigenvector_centrality(A)
# Remove self-loops
for i in range(A.shape[0]):
A[i][i] = 0
fig, ax = plt.subplots(figsize=(8, 10))
plt.axis("off")
color_list = qbn_io.colorise_weights(centrality,beta=False)
qbn_plt.plot_graph(A, X, ax, codes,
layout_type='spring',
layout_seed=5432167,
tol=0.0,
node_color_list=color_list)
plt.show()
Label | Sector | Label | Sector | Label | Sector |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
ag | Agriculture | wh | Wholesale | pr | Professional Services |
mi | Mining | re | Retail | ed | Education & Health |
ut | Utilities | tr | Transportation | ar | Arts & Entertainment |
co | Construction | in | Information | ot | Other Services (exc govt) |
ma | Manufacturing | fi | Finance | go | Government |
An arrow from
Economies are characterised by many such links.
A basic framework for their analysis is Leontief's input-output model.
After introducing the input-output model, we describe some of its connections to {doc}linear programming lecture <lp_intro>
.
Let
-
$x_0$ be the amount of a single exogenous input to production, say labor -
$x_j, j = 1,\ldots n$ be the gross output of final good$j$ -
$d_j, j = 1,\ldots n$ be the net output of final good$j$ that is available for final consumption - $z_{ij} $ be the quantity of good
$i$ allocated to be an input to producing good$j$ for$i=1, \ldots n$ ,$j = 1, \ldots n$ -
$z_{0j}$ be the quantity of labor allocated to producing good$j$ . -
$a_{ij}$ be the number of units of good$i$ required to produce one unit of good$j$ ,$i=0, \ldots, n, j= 1, \ldots n$ . -
$w >0$ be an exogenous wage of labor, denominated in dollars per unit of labor -
$p$ be an$n \times 1$ vector of prices of produced goods$i = 1, \ldots , n$ .
The technology for producing good
To illustrate, we begin by setting
:tags: [hide-input]
G = nx.DiGraph()
nodes= (1, 2, 'c')
edges = ((1, 1), (1, 2), (2, 1), (2, 2), (1, 'c'), (2, 'c'))
edges1 = ((1, 1), (1, 2), (2, 1), (2, 2), (1, 'c'))
edges2 = [(2,'c')]
G.add_nodes_from(nodes)
G.add_edges_from(edges)
pos_list = ([0, 0], [2, 0], [1, -1])
pos = dict(zip(G.nodes(), pos_list))
fig, ax = plt.subplots()
plt.axis("off")
nx.draw_networkx_nodes(G, pos=pos, node_size=800,
node_color='white', edgecolors='black')
nx.draw_networkx_labels(G, pos=pos)
nx.draw_networkx_edges(G,pos=pos, edgelist=edges1,
node_size=300, connectionstyle='arc3,rad=0.2',
arrowsize=10, min_target_margin=15)
nx.draw_networkx_edges(G, pos=pos, edgelist=edges2,
node_size=300, connectionstyle='arc3,rad=-0.2',
arrowsize=10, min_target_margin=15)
plt.text(0.055, 0.125, r'$z_{11}$')
plt.text(1.825, 0.125, r'$z_{22}$')
plt.text(0.955, 0.1, r'$z_{21}$')
plt.text(0.955, -0.125, r'$z_{12}$')
plt.text(0.325, -0.5, r'$d_{1}$')
plt.text(1.6, -0.5, r'$d_{2}$')
plt.show()
Feasible allocations must satisfy
This can be graphically represented as follows.
:tags: [hide-input]
fig, ax = plt.subplots()
ax.grid()
# Draw constraint lines
ax.hlines(0, -1, 400)
ax.vlines(0, -1, 200)
ax.plot(np.linspace(55, 380, 100), (50-0.9*np.linspace(55, 380, 100))/(-1.46), color="r")
ax.plot(np.linspace(-1, 400, 100), (60+0.16*np.linspace(-1, 400, 100))/0.83, color="r")
ax.plot(np.linspace(250, 395, 100), (62-0.04*np.linspace(250, 395, 100))/0.33, color="b")
ax.text(130, 38, r"$(1-a_{11})x_1 + a_{12}x_2 \geq d_1$", size=10)
ax.text(10, 105, r"$-a_{21}x_1 + (1-a_{22})x_2 \geq d_2$", size=10)
ax.text(150, 150, r"$a_{01}x_1 +a_{02}x_2 \leq x_0$", size=10)
# Draw the feasible region
feasible_set = Polygon(np.array([[301, 151],
[368, 143],
[250, 120]]),
color="cyan")
ax.add_patch(feasible_set)
# Draw the optimal solution
ax.plot(250, 120, "*", color="black")
ax.text(260, 115, "solution", size=10)
plt.show()
+++ {"user_expressions": []}
More generally, constraints on production are
$$ \begin{aligned} (I - A) x & \geq d \cr a_0^\top x & \leq x_0 \end{aligned} $$ (eq:inout_1)
where
If we solve the first block of equations of {eq}eq:inout_1
for gross output
$$ x = (I -A)^{-1} d \equiv L d $$ (eq:inout_2)
where the matrix
To assure that the solution eq:inout_2
is a positive vector, the following Hawkins-Simon conditions suffice:
:label: io_ex_tg
For example a two-good economy described by
$$
A =
\begin{bmatrix}
0.1 & 40 \\
0.01 & 0
\end{bmatrix}
\text{ and }
d =
\begin{bmatrix}
50 \\
2
\end{bmatrix}
$$ (eq:inout_ex)
A = np.array([[0.1, 40],
[0.01, 0]])
d = np.array([50, 2]).reshape((2, 1))
I = np.identity(2)
B = I - A
B
Let's check the Hawkins-Simon conditions
np.linalg.det(B) > 0 # checking Hawkins-Simon conditions
Now, let's compute the Leontief inverse matrix
L = np.linalg.inv(B) # obtaining Leontief inverse matrix
L
x = L @ d # solving for gross output
x
+++ {"user_expressions": []}
The second equation of {eq}eq:inout_1
can be written
or
$$ A_0^\top d = x_0 $$ (eq:inout_frontier)
where
For
Equation {eq}eq:inout_frontier
sweeps out a production possibility frontier of final consumption bundles
:label: io_ex_ppf
Consider the example in {eq}`eq:inout_ex`.
Suppose we are now given
$$
a_0^\top = \begin{bmatrix}
4 & 100
\end{bmatrix}
$$
Then we can find
a0 = np.array([4, 100])
A0 = a0 @ L
A0
+++ {"user_expressions": []}
Thus, the production possibility frontier for this economy is
+++ {"user_expressions": []}
{cite}DoSSo
argue that relative prices of the
More generally,
which states that the price of each final good equals the total cost
of production, which consists of costs of intermediate inputs
This equation can be written as
$$ (I - A^\top) p = a_0 w $$ (eq:inout_price)
which implies
Notice how {eq}eq:inout_price
with {eq}eq:inout_1
forms a
conjugate pair through the appearance of operators
that are transposes of one another.
This connection surfaces again in a classic linear program and its dual.
A primal problem is
subject to
The associated dual problem is
subject to
The primal problem chooses a feasible production plan to minimize costs for delivering a pre-assigned vector of final goods consumption
The dual problem chooses prices to maximize the value of a pre-assigned vector of final goods
By the strong duality theorem, optimal value of the primal and dual problems coincide:
where
The dual problem can be graphically represented as follows.
:tags: [hide-input]
fig, ax = plt.subplots()
ax.grid()
# Draw constraint lines
ax.hlines(0, -1, 50)
ax.vlines(0, -1, 250)
ax.plot(np.linspace(4.75, 49, 100), (4-0.9*np.linspace(4.75, 49, 100))/(-0.16), color="r")
ax.plot(np.linspace(0, 50, 100), (33+1.46*np.linspace(0, 50, 100))/0.83, color="r")
ax.text(15, 175, r"$(1-a_{11})p_1 - a_{21}p_2 \leq a_{01}w$", size=10)
ax.text(30, 85, r"$-a_{12}p_1 + (1-a_{22})p_2 \leq a_{02}w$", size=10)
# Draw the feasible region
feasible_set = Polygon(np.array([[17, 69],
[4, 0],
[0,0],
[0, 40]]),
color="cyan")
ax.add_patch(feasible_set)
# Draw the optimal solution
ax.plot(17, 69, "*", color="black")
ax.text(18, 60, "dual solution", size=10)
plt.show()
+++ {"user_expressions": []}
We have discussed that gross output eq:inout_2
, where
Recall the {doc}Neumann Series Lemma <eigen_II>
which states that
In fact
Consider the impact of a demand shock
Gross output shifts from
If
This illustrates that an element
We can further study input-output networks through applications of {doc}graph theory <networks>
.
An input-output network can be represented by a weighted directed graph induced by the adjacency matrix
The set of nodes
In {numref}us_15sectors
weights are indicated by the widths of the arrows, which are proportional to the corresponding input-output coefficients.
We can now use centrality measures to rank sectors and discuss their importance relative to the other sectors.
Eigenvector centrality of a node
We plot a bar graph of hub-based eigenvector centrality for the sectors represented in {numref}us_15sectors
.
:tags: [hide-input]
fig, ax = plt.subplots()
ax.bar(codes, centrality, color=color_list, alpha=0.6)
ax.set_ylabel("eigenvector centrality", fontsize=12)
plt.show()
A higher measure indicates higher importance as a supplier.
As a result demand shocks in most sectors will significantly impact activity in sectors with high eigenvector centrality.
The above figure indicates that manufacturing is the most dominant sector in the US economy.
Another way to rank sectors in input-output networks is via output multipliers.
The output multiplier of sector
Earlier when disussing demand shocks we concluded that for
Thus,
This can be written as
Please note that here we use
High ranking sectors within this measure are important buyers of intermediate goods.
A demand shock in such sectors will cause a large impact on the whole production network.
The following figure displays the output multipliers for the sectors represented
in {numref}us_15sectors
.
:tags: [hide-input]
A, F = build_coefficient_matrices(Z, X)
omult = qbn_io.katz_centrality(A, authority=True)
fig, ax = plt.subplots()
omult_color_list = qbn_io.colorise_weights(omult,beta=False)
ax.bar(codes, omult, color=omult_color_list, alpha=0.6)
ax.set_ylabel("Output multipliers", fontsize=12)
plt.show()
We observe that manufacturing and agriculture are highest ranking sectors.
:label: io_ex1
{cite}DoSSo
Chapter 9 discusses an example with the following
parameter settings:
Describe how they infer the input-output coefficients in
where
:class: dropdown
For each
:label: io_ex2
Derive the production possibility frontier for the economy characterized in the previous exercise.
:class: dropdown
A = np.array([[0.1, 1.46],
[0.16, 0.17]])
a_0 = np.array([0.04, 0.33])
I = np.identity(2)
B = I - A
L = np.linalg.inv(B)
A_0 = a_0 @ L
A_0
+++ {"user_expressions": []}
Thus the production possibility frontier is given by